Tax Avoidance and Tax Evasion Explained and Exemplified

Law And Order Criminal Intent Cast - Tax Avoidance and Tax Evasion Explained and Exemplified

Good afternoon. Yesterday, I learned all about Law And Order Criminal Intent Cast - Tax Avoidance and Tax Evasion Explained and Exemplified. Which could be very helpful to me and you. Tax Avoidance and Tax Evasion Explained and Exemplified

Introduction

What I said. It isn't in conclusion that the real about Law And Order Criminal Intent Cast. You look at this article for home elevators an individual wish to know is Law And Order Criminal Intent Cast.

Law And Order Criminal Intent Cast

There is a clear-cut unlikeness in the middle of tax avoidance and tax evasion. One is legally approved and the other is an offense. Unfortunately however many consultants even in this country do not understand the unlikeness in the middle of tax avoidance and tax evasion. Most of the planning aspects that have been suggested by these consultants often fall into the type of tax evasion (which is illegal) and so tends to put clients into a risky situation and also diminish the value of tax planning.

This may be one of the prime reasons where clients have lost faith in tax planning consultants as most of them have often suggested dubious systems which are clearly under the type of tax evasion.

In this lesson I furnish some examples and case studies (including legal cases) of how tax evasion (often suggested by consultants purporting to be specialists in tax planning) is undertaken not only in this country but in many parts of the world. It is true that many citizen do not like to pay their hard-earned money to the government. however doing this in an illegal manner such as by tax evasion is not the answer. Good tax planning involves tax avoidance or the discount of the tax incidence. If this is done properly it can save huge amounts of money in a legally approved way. This lesson also highlights some practical examples and case studies (including legal) of tax avoidance.

Why Governments Need Your Taxes (Basic Economic Arguments)

Income tax the biggest source of government funds today in most countries is a comparatively up-to-date invention, probably because the plan of each year revenue is itself a contemporary concept. Governments beloved to tax things that were easy to measure and on which it was thus easy to conjecture the liability. This is why early taxes concentrated on tangible items such as land and property, corporal goods, commodities and ships, as well as things such as the estimate of windows or fireplaces in a building. In the 20th century, particularly the second half, governments around the world took a growing share of their country's national revenue in tax, mainly to pay for increasingly more expensive defense efforts and for a contemporary welfare state. Indirect tax on consumption, such as value-added tax, has come to be increasingly prominent as direct taxation on revenue and wealth has come to be increasingly unpopular. But big differences among countries remain. One is the allembracing level of tax. For example, in United States tax revenue amounts to around one-third of its Gdp (gross domestic product), whereas in Sweden it is closer to half.

Others are the beloved methods of collecting it (direct versus indirect), the rates at which it is levied and the definition of the tax base to which these rates are applied. Countries have dissimilar attitudes to progressive and regressive taxation. There are also big differences in the way accountability for taxation is divided among dissimilar levels of government. Arguably agreeing to the discipline of economics any tax is a bad tax. But collective goods and other government activities have to be paid for somehow, and economists often have strong views on which methods of taxation are more or less efficient. Most economists agree that the best tax is one that has as tiny impact as inherent on people's decisions about whether to undertake a effective economic activity. High rates of tax on labour may discourage citizen from working, and so effect in lower tax revenue than there would be if the tax rate were lower, an idea captured in the Laffer curve in economics theory.

Certainly, the marginal rate of tax may have a bigger effect on incentives than the allembracing tax burden. Land tax is regarded as the most effective by some economists and tax on expenditure by others, as it does all the taking after the wealth creation is done. Some economists favor a neutral tax theory that does not affect the sorts of economic activities that take place. Others favor using tax, and tax breaks, to guide economic activity in ways they favor, such as to minimize pollution and to growth the amenity of employing citizen rather than capital. Some economists argue that the tax theory should be characterized by both horizontal equity and vertical equity, because this is fair, and because when the tax theory is fair citizen may find it harder to illustrate tax evasion or avoidance.

However, who finally pays (the tax incidence) may be dissimilar from who is initially charged, if that man can pass it on, say by adding the tax to the price he charges for his output. Taxes on companies, for example, are all the time paid in the end by humans, be they workers, customers or shareholders. You should note that taxation and its role in economics is a very wide branch and this book does not address the issues of taxation and economics but rather tax planning to enhance your economic position. however if you are curious in insight the role of taxation in economics you should consult a good book on economics which often talks about the impact of dissimilar types of taxation on the economic activities of a nation of society.

Tax Avoidance and Evasion

Tax avoidance can be summed as doing all inherent within the law to sacrifice your tax bill. Learned Hand, an American judge, once said that there is nothing sinister in so arranging one's affairs as to keep taxes as low as inherent as nobody owes any collective duty to pay more than the law demands. On the other hand tax evasion can be defined as paying less tax than you are legally obliged to. There may be a thin line in the middle of the two, but as Denis Healey, a previous British chancellor, once put it, "The unlikeness in the middle of tax avoidance and tax evasion is the thickness of a prison wall." The courts recognize the fact that no taxpayer is obliged to dispose his/her affairs so as to maximize the tax the government receives. Individuals and businesses are entitled to take all lawful steps to minimize their taxes.

A taxpayer may lawfully dispose her affairs to minimize taxes by such steps as deferring revenue from one year to the next. It is lawful to take all ready tax deductions. It is also lawful to avoid taxes by development charitable contributions. Tax evasion, on the other hand, is a crime. Tax evasion typically involves failing to article income, or improperly claiming deductions that are not authorized. Examples of tax evasion consist of such actions as when a contractor "forgets" to article the Lkr 1, 000,000 cash he receives for construction a pool, or when a business owner tries to deduct Lkr 1, 000,000 of personal expenses from his business taxes, or when a man falsely claims she made charitable contributions, or significantly overestimates the value of asset donated to charity.

Similarly, if an estate is worth Lkr 5,000,000 and the executor files a false tax return, improperly omitting asset and claiming the estate is only worth Lkr 100,000, thus owing much less in taxes. Tax evasion has an impact on our tax system. It causes a primary loss of revenue to the community that could be used for funding improvements in health, education, and other government programs. Tax evasion also allows some businesses to gain an unfair benefit in a contentious shop and some individuals to not meet their tax obligations. As a result, the burden of tax not paid by those who select to evade tax falls on other law abiding taxpayers.

Examples of tax evasion are: ï?~ Failing to declare assessable revenue ï?~ Claiming deductions for expenses that were not incurred or are not legally deductible ï?~ Claiming input earnings for goods that Value Added Tax (Vat)has not been paid on ï?~ Failing to pay the Paye (pay as you earn a form of with keeping tax)installments that have been deducted from a payment, for example tax taken out of a worker's wages ï?~ Failing to lodge tax returns in an effort to avoid payment. The following are some signs that a man or business may be evading tax: ï?~ Not being registered for Vat despite clearly exceeding the threshold ï?~ Not charging Vat at the definite rate ï?~ Not wanting to issue a receipt ï?~ Providing false invoices ï?~ Using a false business name, address, or taxpayers identification estimate (Tin) and Vat registration estimate ï?~ keeping two sets of accounts, and ï?~ Not providing staff with payment summaries

Legal Aspects of Tax Avoidance and Tax Evasion Two normal points can be made about tax avoidance and evasion. First, tax avoidance or evasion occurs over the tax spectrum and is not peculiar to any tax type such as import taxes, stamp duties, Vat, Paye and revenue tax. Secondly, legislation that addresses avoidance or evasion must necessarily be imprecise. No prescriptive set of rules exists for determining when a singular arrangement amounts to tax avoidance or evasion. This lack of precision creates uncertainty and adds to compliance costs both to the branch of Inland revenue and the tax payer.

Definitions of Tax Mitigation Avoidance and Evasion It is impossible to express a definite test as to whether taxpayers have avoided, evaded or merely mitigated their tax obligations. As Baragwanath J said in Miller v Cir; McDougall v Cir: What is legitimate 'mitigation'(meaning avoidance) and what is illegitimate 'avoidance'(meaning evasion) is in the end to be decided by the Commissioner, the Taxation report Authority and finally the courts, as a matter of judgment. Please note in the above statement the words are in fact as stated in judgment. however there is a mix-up of words which have been clarified by the words in the brackets by me. Tax Mitigation (Avoidance by Planning) Taxpayers are entitled to mitigate their liability to tax and will not be vulnerable to the normal anti-avoidance rules in a statute. A article of tax mitigation was given by Lord Templeman in Cir v Challenge Corporate Ltd: revenue tax is mitigated by a taxpayer who reduces his revenue or incurs expenditure in circumstances which sacrifice his assessable revenue or entitle him to discount in his tax liability.

Tax mitigation is, therefore, behavior which, without amounting to tax avoidance (by planning), serves to attract less liability than otherwise might have arisen. Tax Avoidance Tax evasion, as Lord Templeman has pointed out, is not mere mitigation. The term is described directly or indirectly by ï?~ Altering the incidence of any revenue tax ï?~ Relieving any man from liability to pay revenue tax ï?~ Avoiding, reducing or postponing any liability to revenue tax On an excessively literal interpretation, this coming could conceivably apply to mere mitigation, for example, to an individual's decision not to work overtime, because the further revenue would attract a higher rate of tax. However, a great way of approaching tax avoidance is to regard it as an arrangement that, unlike mitigation, yields results that Parliament did not intend.

In Challenge Corporation Ltd v Cir, Cooke J described the effect of the normal anti-avoidance rules in these terms: [It] nullifies against the Commissioner for revenue tax purposes any arrangement to the extent that it has a purpose or effect of tax avoidance, unless that purpose or effect is merely incidental. Where an arrangement is void the Commissioner is given power to adjust the assessable revenue of any man affected by it, so as to counteract any tax benefit obtained by that person. Woodhouse J commented on the breadth of the normal anti-avoidance rule in the Challenge Corporation case, noting that Parliament had taken: The deliberate decision that because the question of definition in this elusive field cannot be met by expressly spelling out a series of detailed specifications in the statute itself, the interstices must be left for concentration by the judges.

Tax Evasion Mitigation and avoidance are concepts concerned with whether or not a tax liability has arisen. With evasion, the beginning point is all the time that a liability has arisen. The ask is whether that liability has been illegitimately, even criminally been left unsatisfied. In Cir v Challenge Corporation Ltd, Lord Templeman said: Evasion occurs when the Commissioner is not informed of all the facts relevant to an evaluation of tax. Innocent evasion may lead to a re-assessment. Fraudulent evasion may lead to a criminal prosecution as well as re-assessment.

The elements which can attract the criminal label to evasion were elaborated by Dickson J in Denver Chemical Manufacturing v Commissioner of Taxation (New South Wales): An intention to maintain facts lest the Commissioner should think the taxpayer liable to a greater extent than the taxpayer is ready to concede, is conduct which if the effect is to avoid tax would illustrate seeing evasion. Not all evasion is fraudulent. It becomes fraudulent if it involves a deliberate effort to cheat the revenue. On the other hand, evasion may exist, but may not be fraudulent, if it is the effect of a genuine mistake. In order to prove the offence of evasion, the Commissioner must show intent to evade by the taxpayer. As with other offences, this intent may be inferred from the circumstances of the singular case. Tax avoidance and tax mitigation are mutually exclusive. Tax avoidance and tax evasion are not: They may both arise out of the same situation. For example, a taxpayer files a tax return based on the effectiveness of a transaction which is known to be void against the Commissioner as a tax avoidance arrangement.

A senior United Kingdom tax lawful recently referred to this issue: If an 'avoidance' project relies on misrepresentation, deception and concealment of the full facts, then avoidance is a misnomer; the project would be more accurately described as fraud, and would fall to be dealt with as such. Where fraud is involved, it cannot be re-characterized as avoidance by cloaking the behavior with synthetic structures, contrived transactions and esoteric arguments as to how the tax law should be applied to the structures and transactions. Tax Avoidance in a course Framework We now turn from the existing legal framework in the context of revenue tax to a inherent course framework for considering issues relating to tax avoidance generally. The questions determined relevant to a course pathology of tax avoidance are: What is tax avoidance? Under what conditions is tax avoidance possible? When is tax avoidance a 'policy problem? What is a sensible course response to tax avoidance?

What is the value of, and what are the limitations of, normal anti-avoidance rules? The first two questions are discussed below What is Tax Avoidance? Finance literature may offer some advice to what is meant by tax avoidance in its definition of 'arbitrage'. Arbitrage is a means of profiting from a mismatch in prices. An example is seeing and exploiting price differences in the middle of New Zealand and Australia in shares in the same listed company. A real value can be found in such arbitrage activity, since it spreads facts about prices. ask for the low-priced goods increases and ask for the high-priced goods decreases, ensuring that goods and resources are put to their best use. Tax arbitrage is, therefore, a form of tax planning. It is an activity directed towards the discount of tax. It is this plan of tax arbitrage that seems to constitute commonly approved notions of what is tax avoidance. Activities such as giving money to charity or investing in tax-preferred sectors, would not fall into this definition of tax arbitrage, and thus would not be tax avoidance even if the activity were motivated by tax considerations. It has been noted that financial arbitrage can have a beneficial economic function. The same may be true of tax arbitrage, presuming that differences in taxation are deliberate government course furthering economic efficiency.

It is inherent that tax arbitrage directs resources into activities with low tax rates, as intended by government policy. It is also likely to ensure that investors in tax-preferred areas are those who can benefit most from the tax concessions, namely, those facing the highest marginal tax rates. If government course objectives are great achieved, tax arbitrage is in accordance with the government's course intent. Tax avoidance, then, can be viewed as a form of tax arbitrage that is contrary to legislative or course intent. What Makes Tax Avoidance Possible? The basic ingredients of tax arbitrage are the plan of arbitrage, and the possibilities of profiting from differentials that the plan of arbitrage implies. This definition leads to the view that three conditions need to be gift for tax avoidance to exist. A unlikeness in the effective marginal tax rates on economic revenue is required. For arbitrage to exist, there must be a price differential and, in tax arbitrage, this is a tax differential. Such tax differences can arise because of a variable rate structure, such as a progressive rate scale, or rate differences applying to dissimilar taxpayers, such as tax-exempt bodies or tax loss companies.

Alternatively it can arise because the tax base is less than comprehensive, for example, because not all economic revenue is branch to revenue tax.

o An ability to exploit the unlikeness in tax by converting high-tax activity into low-tax activity is required. If there are differences in tax rates, but no ability to move from high to low-tax, no arbitrage is possible.
o Even if these two conditions are met, this does not make tax arbitrage and avoidance possible. The tax theory may mix high and low-rate taxpayers. The high-rate taxpayer may be able to divert revenue to a low-rate taxpayer or turn highly-taxed revenue into a lowly-taxed form. But this is pointless unless the high-rate taxpayer can be recompensed in a lowly-taxed form for diverting or converting his or her revenue into a low-tax category. The revenue must come back in a low-tax form. The benefit must also exceed the transaction costs. This is the third primary condition for tax arbitrage.
o Since all tax systems have tax bases (The thing or estimate to which a tax rate applies.

To derive revenue tax, for example, you need a meaningful definition of income. Definitions of the tax base can vary enormously, over time and among countries, especially when tax breaks are taken into account. As a result, a country with a comparatively high tax rate may not have a high tax burden (Total tax paid in a period as a proportion of total revenue in that period. It can refer to personal, corporate or national income. ) if it has a more narrowly defined tax base than other countries. In up-to-date years, the political unpopularity of high tax rates has lead many governments to lower rates and at the same time broaden the tax base, often leaving the tax burden unchanged. )that are less than allembracing because of the impossibility of defining and measuring all economic income, tax arbitrage and avoidance is inherent in tax systems. Examples of Tax Arbitrage/Avoidance The simplest form of arbitrage involves a house unit or a singular taxpayer. If that house unit or taxpayer faces differences in tax rates (condition 1 above), and condition 2 above applies, then the third condition automatically holds.

This closing follows because citizen can all the time compensate themselves for converting or diverting revenue to a low tax rate. An example of such easy tax arbitrage spicy a house unit is revenue splitting through, for example, the use of house trust. An example of easy tax arbitrage spicy a singular taxpayer is a straddle whereby a dealer in financial assets brings send losses on, say shares, and defers gains while retaining an economic interest in the shares straight through use of options. Transfer pricing and thin capitalization practices straight through which non-residents minimize their tax liabilities are more sophisticated examples of the same principles. Multi-party arbitrage is more complex; the complexity is made primary by the need to meet condition 3 above, that is, to ensure a net gain accrues to the high-rate taxpayer. In the simpler cases of multi-party revenue tax arbitrage, this process normally involves a tax-exempt (or tax-loss or tax-haven) entity and a taxpaying entity. revenue is diverted to the tax-exempt entity and expenses are diverted to the taxpaying entity. Finally, the taxpaying entity is compensated for diverting revenue and assuming expenses by receiving non-taxable revenue or a non-taxable benefit, such as a capital gain.

Over the years many have indulged in numerous examples of such tax arbitrage using elements in the legislation at the time. Examples are finance leasing, non-recourse lending, tax-haven(a country or designated zone that has low or no taxes, or highly secretive banks and often a warm climate and sandy beaches, which make it spicy to foreigners bent on tax avoidance and evasion ) 'investments' and redeemable preference shares. Low-tax policies pursued by some countries in the hope of attracting international businesses and capital is called tax competition which can furnish a rich ground for arbitrage. Economists normally favour competition in any form. But some say that tax competition is often a beggar-thy-neighbor policy, which can sacrifice someone else country's tax base, or force it to turn its mix of taxes, or stop it taxing in the way it would like.

Economists who favour tax competition often cite a 1956 article by Charles Tiebout (1924-68) entitled "A Pure theory of Local Expenditures". In it he argued that, faced with a option of dissimilar combinations of tax and government services, taxpayers will select to search where they get closest to the combination they want. Variations in tax rates among dissimilar countries are good, because they give taxpayers more option and thus more chance of being satisfied. This also puts pressure on governments to be efficient. Thus measures to harmonize taxes are a bad idea. There is at least one big caveat to this theory. Tiebout assumed, crucially, that taxpayers are highly mobile and able to move to wherever their beloved combination of taxes and benefits is on offer.

Tax competition may make it harder to redistribute from rich to poor straight through the tax theory by allowing the rich to move to where taxes are not redistributive. Tactics Used by Tax Evaders Moonlighting Tax evasion at its simplest level merely involves staying out of the tax theory altogether. The revenue deploys small teams of volunteer officers to carry out lookout to track down moonlighters. Early success was followed up by the deployment of compliance officers in virtually every tax office. revenue Investigation Officers routinely scan advertisements in local newspapers or shop windows and even before the arrival of the contemporary personal computer they oftentimes had passage to reverse telephone directories to track down moonlighters from bare telephone estimate details. They also study bank and other financial institutions deposit and loans databases, customs records, and star class hotel bookings for inexpressive functions and ceremonies to recognize rich individuals who maybe evading taxes.

Non Extractive Fraud Alternatively it can arise because the tax base is less than comprehensive, for example, because not all economic revenue is branch to revenue tax. ï?~ An ability to exploit the unlikeness in tax by converting high-tax activity into low-tax activity is required. If there are differences in tax rates, but no ability to move from high to low-tax, no arbitrage is possible. ï?~ Even if these two conditions are met, this does not make tax arbitrage and avoidance possible. The tax theory may mix high and low-rate taxpayers. The high-rate taxpayer may be able to divert revenue to a low-rate taxpayer or turn highly-taxed revenue into a lowly-taxed form. But this is pointless unless the high-rate taxpayer can be recompensed in a lowly-taxed form for diverting or converting his or her revenue into a low-tax category. The revenue must come back in a low-tax form. The benefit must also exceed the transaction costs. This is the third primary condition for tax arbitrage. Since all tax systems have bases that are less than allembracing because of the impossibility of defining and measuring all economic income, tax arbitrage and avoidance is inherent in tax systems. This involves behalf switches or timing differences, for example:

o Post dating Receipts
o Ante dating Expenditure
o inexpressive Reserves
o Incorrect accounting of transactions such as showing an revenue as a payable.
o Stock manipulation possibly the most tasteless place recipe seen in convention is the manipulation of stock to produce the desired "profit".

It is not unknown for the evaders' Accountant to be involved - putting at risk the livelihood and, if the estimate involved is significant, personal liberty! The most blatant case of this kind is where the Accountant virtually treated this as year end tax planning. Based upon the formal disclosures made by the evader under the Hansard course to the Inland revenue (in which he concerned the Accountant and in relationship with an list in a false name also his Bank Manager), the following scene can be recreated: "Studying the draft accounts the Accountant did a quick calculation to work out what range of figures could be used for closing stock in hand without giving rise to suspicion. He then apparently discussed with the client the impact on net behalf of reducing closing Stock.

Arrangements were then made for the audit to take place and in the meantime some stock was moved off site! "The Accountant and Bank manager who assisted the evader are both guilty of conspiracy to defraud - it matters not that they made no financial gain themselves. Extractive Fraud This might take the form of Suppressed receipts or inflated outgoings: Suppressed Receipts Typically these involve defected mainstream takings and often an undisclosed bank account. however the more resourceful evader may take benefit of special arrangements or unexpected receipts: Where the proprietor or director personally deals with some customers it may be inherent for cheques to be made out in a manner which facilitates diversion. Alternatively cheque substitution may be used, such that the otherwise "off article sale" cheque is banked and an equivalent estimate of "on article cash" is extracted.

It is not unknown for late cash payment of prestige sales to bypass the bookkeeping theory with the debt subsequently being written off as bad. Unexpected receipts all the time gift a good chance for deflection. For example:

1. Scrap sales
2. Guarnatee or bad debt recoveries
3. Refunds, rebates or discounts
4. Returned goods sold for cash, disposal of fully written down assets and windfalls in general.

The evader may take benefit of a new business opportunity, which remains hidden, and off record. Examples of this seen in convention include:

1. The dentist with three practices of which only two were discloses
2. The off article sale of hitherto obsolete car parts to the burgeoning superior car shop Inflated Purchases & Expenses Where the ability to deflect receipts is too difficult the evader might draw cash from the business bank list and disguise such withdrawals as some form of legitimate business expense. In convention this often involves the use of "ghost" employees or fictitious outgoings to cover such extractions. Fictitious outgoings have to hire the use of false invoices. These might take the form of altered invoices, photocopied or even scanned "blanked" versions of genuine invoices, thoroughly bogus invoices or even blank invoices supplied by an associate.

Another coming seen in convention involved the use of a seemingly unconnected off shore business to raise invoices for fictitious services. To hide the true rights of the off shore business the evader uses a "black hole" trust to hold the shares. Essentially this involved a compliant non-resident trustee and "dummy" settler - the trustee providing "stooge" directors as part of the arrangements.

Employment Tax Evasion Schemes Employment tax evasion schemes can take a range of forms. Some of the more prevalent methods of evasion consist of pyramiding, laborer leasing, paying employees in cash, filing false payroll tax returns or failing to file payroll tax returns. Pyramiding "Pyramiding" of employment taxes is a fraudulent convention where a business withholds taxes from its employees but intentionally fails to remit them to the relevant departments. Businesses involved in pyramiding oftentimes file for bankruptcy to extraction the liabilities accrued and then start a new business under a dissimilar name and begin a new scheme. Employment Leasing laborer leasing is someone else legal business practice, which is sometimes branch to abuse.

Employee leasing is the convention of contracting with exterior businesses to deal with all administrative, personnel, and payroll concerns for employees. In some instances, employee-leasing fellowships fail to pay over to the authorities any measure of the collected employment taxes. These taxes are often spent by the owners on business or personal expenses. Often the business dissolves, leaving millions in employment taxes unpaid. Paying Employees in Cash Paying employees in whole or partially in cash is a tasteless recipe of evading revenue and employment taxes resulting in lost tax revenue to the government and the loss or discount of hereafter collective benefits. Filing False Payroll Tax Returns or Failing to File Payroll Tax Returns preparation false payroll tax returns understating the estimate of wages on which taxes are owed, or failing to file employment tax returns are methods commonly used to evade employment taxes. Payments of Benefits These consist of free benefits such as personal entertainment, immoderate allowances for foreign travel, provision of educational schemes (foreign education) to only beloved employees, car and driver paid by business etc are easy examples.

Conclusion

I hope that I have made clear the unlikeness in the middle of doing things right and in fact and in a fraudulent manner. whether you are a taxpayer or a counselor it is prominent to make sure that you understand the nuances of good tax planning. Whilst it is understood that tax planning is becoming more difficult and there is only a thin line in the middle of what is right and wrong it obviously requires the expert to do the needful. however be specific not to be tricked by those who claim to be experts in tax planning when they are mere computational experts.

I hope you have new knowledge about Law And Order Criminal Intent Cast. Where you possibly can offer use within your daily life. And most importantly, your reaction is passed about Law And Order Criminal Intent Cast.

0 comments:

Post a Comment